• Coin Juncture
  • Posts
  • How Government is the Invisible Hand in Your Life

How Government is the Invisible Hand in Your Life

The Free Market Fallacy: How Government Became the Invisible Hand

The Great Economic Catfish

Have you ever been catfished? That "free market" you've heard so much about has been wearing a pretty convincing disguise.

Imagine dating someone who claims to be "totally independent" but actually lives with their parents, drives their parents' car, and has their bills paid by their parents.

That's essentially modern capitalism: loudly proclaiming its free-market credentials while government intervention shapes nearly every aspect of economic life.

This isn't just clever wordplay—it's backed by hard data.


Government spending across developed economies has ballooned from 26.9% of GDP in 1960 to a whopping 42.5% by 2019.

Meanwhile, central banks have transformed from modest referees to star players, with the Federal Reserve's balance sheet expanding by 900% since 2007.

So how did we get here? Is this intervention helpful or harmful? And what should the relationship between markets and government actually look like?

A Quick History of Economic Hand-Holding

The Original Economic Influencer:

When Adam Smith wrote about the "invisible hand" in 1776, he envisioned markets where private buyers and sellers would determine prices with minimal government meddling. This approach dominated economic thinking throughout much of the 19th century.

But even during this supposed golden age of free markets:

  • The U.S. government handed railroads over 130 million acres of land (an area larger than California and Maine combined)

  • Britain implemented factory regulations despite free-market purists clutching their pearls

  • Tariffs remained common tools of economic policy

The purely "free" market has always been more myth than reality.

Markets Face Their Midlife Crisis

Then came the mother of all market failures. The stock market crash of 1929 and the subsequent Great Depression saw:

  • Unemployment skyrocketed to 25% by 1933

  • Industrial production collapsed by 45%

  • Banks fail by the thousands

When markets failed to self-correct (despite classical economists insisting they would), economist John Maynard Keynes stepped in with a radical idea: maybe governments should actively manage economies during downturns.

Franklin D. Roosevelt's New Deal put this theory into practice, employing 8.5 million Americans through the Works Progress Administration and establishing Social Security. This was a fundamental rethinking of the government's economic role.

From Mixed Economy to Government on Steroids

The decades following World War II (1945-1970s) brought unprecedented prosperity under "mixed economies" that combined markets with significant government involvement. However, starting in the 1980s, political leaders like Ronald Reagan and Margaret Thatcher promised to roll back government and unleash free markets.

Despite all the free-market rhetoric, government intervention expanded in new and more sophisticated ways:

  • 2008 Financial Crisis: A $700 billion bailout for financial institutions that had gambled and lost

  • COVID-19 Pandemic: A staggering $16.9 trillion in global fiscal support (16% of global GDP)

  • Federal Reserve's Balance Sheet: Expanded from $900 billion in 2007 to nearly $9 trillion in 2022

Actions speak louder than words, and the actions say government intervention is the new normal.

The Government's Market Manipulation Toolkit

1. Fiscal Policy: Your Tax Dollars at Work (Sometimes)

Governments shape markets through taxing and spending, including:

Progressive taxation: Highest marginal rates vary dramatically—from 57.1% in Sweden to 37% in the U.S. (2022)

Targeted subsidies: Some are jaw-dropping:

  • Global fossil fuel subsidies: $5.9 trillion (6.8% of global GDP) in 2020

  • Agricultural subsidies across developed countries: Over $500 billion annually

Infrastructure spending: The 2021 U.S. Infrastructure Investment and Jobs Act allocated $1.2 trillion for transportation, utilities, and broadband—about $3,600 for every American.

2. Monetary Policy: The Money Magicians

Central banks have gone from boring institutions to economic celebrities:

Interest rate manipulation: The Federal Reserve kept rates near zero for years after the 2008 crisis and again during COVID-19. Imagine your friend controlling the price of everything from mortgages to car loans nationwide.

Quantitative easing (QE): Central banks printed trillions to buy assets—expanding the ECB's balance sheet from €1.2 trillion in 2007 to €8.8 trillion by 2022. That's like creating the entire economic output of Germany out of thin air.

Forward guidance: Central banks now telegraph their future moves, creating what economists call "the Jedi mind trick" of monetary policy: "These are not the interest rates you're looking for."

3. Regulations: The Economic Rulebook

Government rules shape how markets function:

Antitrust enforcement: In 2023, the U.S. Department of Justice sued Google for allegedly controlling 90% of the search market. That's like owning the board, the dice, and the rule book in Monopoly.

Environmental regulations: The EU's Emissions Trading System covers 40% of European greenhouse gas emissions, creating a market-based approach to pollution control.

Labor market regulations: The strictness varies dramatically—France's employment protection index is 2.6 compared to just 0.5 in the United States. That's the difference between "you're hired" and "let me consult with our legal team first."

When Government Plays Market God

The Swedish Carbon Tax: A Rare Policy Home Run

Sweden's carbon tax proves government intervention can occasionally hit the bullseye:

  • Implementation: Started modestly at €24 per ton of CO₂ in 1991, gradually increasing to €114 by 2020

  • Results: Carbon emissions fell 27% while GDP grew 78% between 1990-2018

  • Secret sauce: Gradual implementation, revenue neutrality, and complementary policies

This success story shows that when designed well, interventions addressing specific market failures (like pollution) can work without tanking the economy.

Renewable Energy Subsidies: It's Complicated

Government support for renewable energy shows the mixed bag that interventions often are:

  • The good: Solar PV costs plummeted 85% between 2010-2020 thanks in part to $160 billion in global subsidies

  • The bad: China's aggressive subsidies created manufacturing overcapacity, bankrupting Western competitors

  • The reality: By 2021, Chinese manufacturers controlled 80% of global solar panel production

Subsidies can accelerate innovation but create market distortions and geopolitical headaches without careful international coordination.

Bangladesh's Onion Fiasco: How Not to Intervene

When Bangladesh imposed price caps on onions in 2023, Economics 101 played out in real-time:

  • Hoarding became widespread

  • Black markets flourished

  • Actual availability at official prices plummeted

It's the economic equivalent of pushing on a water balloon—squeeze prices in one place, and they bulge somewhere else.

The 2008 Financial Crisis: The Intervention Paradox

The response to the 2008 meltdown reveals the complexity of evaluating government action:

  • Short-term win: Emergency interventions prevented a complete collapse. Research estimates that without them, U.S. GDP would have cratered by 14% instead of 4%, with 8.5 million additional job losses.

  • Long-term problem: These same interventions may have encouraged more reckless behavior. The five largest U.S. banks now control 47% of banking assets (up from 30% in 2000), creating even bigger "too-big-to-fail" institutions.

  • Financial plot twist: While controversial at the time, many bailout programs ultimately returned profits to taxpayers. TARP's bank programs generated a $24 billion profit, though the overall program lost about $31 billion.

This case shows the challenge in evaluating interventions where immediate necessities may create long-term problems.

When Government Intervention Makes Sense (Sometimes)

The Public Goods Problem

Some things markets genuinely struggle to provide efficiently:

  • Public goods: Things like national defense and basic research that benefit everyone and can't easily exclude non-payers.

  • Merit goods: Education and healthcare generate benefits beyond the individual consumer.

  • Natural monopolies: Services like water or electricity distribution where competition actually creates inefficiency.

But even here, the implementation gets messy:

  • That $886 billion U.S. defense budget (2023) mostly flows to private contractors like Lockheed Martin

  • Public infrastructure projects typically cost 20-30% more and take 20-30% longer than comparable private projects

  • Without profit and loss to guide decisions, public providers need alternative accountability systems that often function...imperfectly

The Case Against Playing Economic Puppet Master

When Signals Get Scrambled

Markets function through price signals—like a vast communication network. Government intervention often garbles these signals:

  • Interest rate manipulation: Ultra-low rates from 2008-2022 fueled asset bubbles but failed to boost productivity growth, which remained sluggish at 1.4% annually (below the historical average of 2.1%).

  • Malinvestment: Subsidies can attract too much capital to favored sectors. Research suggests renewable energy subsidies reduced private R&D in other energy technologies by about 7%.

  • Inequality accelerant: The Federal Reserve's asset purchases disproportionately benefited the wealthy. From 2009-2020, the top 1% captured approximately 52% of total wealth gains in the U.S.

Politics and Economics: A Dysfunctional Marriage

Public choice theory explains why government interventions often fail to serve the public interest:

  • Concentrated benefits, diffuse costs: U.S. sugar import restrictions cost consumers approximately $3.7 billion annually while benefiting a small number of producers—but guess who lobbies harder?

  • Regulatory capture: Industries influence the agencies meant to regulate them. Over 75% of former SEC lawyers go on to represent clients before the SEC within a year of leaving.

  • Rent-seeking: Companies invest in securing government benefits rather than creating value. Lobbying in the U.S. provides returns of 22,000% on investment, making "government relations" often more profitable than actual innovation.

When Help Becomes a Crutch

Government support can create problematic incentive structures:

  • Too-big-to-fail doctrine: Financial institutions deemed "systemically important" receive an implicit subsidy worth approximately $70 billion annually in the U.S. by being able to borrow at lower rates due to the expectation of government bailouts.

  • Temporary becomes permanent: The U.S. Export-Import Bank, created as a "temporary" New Deal agency in 1934, is still going strong nearly 90 years later. As Milton Friedman quipped, "Nothing is so permanent as a temporary government program."

Finding the Sweet Spot: Smart Intervention

Between laissez-faire fantasy and command-economy nightmare lies a more pragmatic approach:

Target Real Problems, Not Symptoms

Effective interventions address specific, well-defined market failures:

  • Externalities: When markets don't account for social costs or benefits. The social cost of carbon emissions is estimated at $51-$185 per ton, but without intervention, markets price this at zero.

  • Information asymmetries: When parties have unequal information. Financial disclosure requirements improve market efficiency by reducing information asymmetries and lowering capital costs by 0.1-0.6%.

Design Matters More Than Dogma

How interventions are structured often determines success or failure:

  • Work with markets, not against them: Carbon taxes generally outperform command-and-control regulations because they harness rather than fight market forces.

  • Evidence-based approaches: Randomized controlled trials in development economics have revolutionized antipoverty programs by identifying which interventions deliver the most bang for the buck.

  • Sunset provisions: Automatically expiring programs reduce the risk of permanent dependencies. The 2020 CARES Act's enhanced unemployment benefits included specific expiration dates to prevent indefinite continuation.

Principles for Better Government Intervention

If we accept that some intervention is inevitable (and occasionally beneficial), how should it be designed?

1. Surgical, Not Shotgun

Effective interventions target specific problems with minimal collateral damage:

  • Precision over breadth: Earned income tax credits specifically address working poverty without distorting labor markets as significantly as minimum wages.

  • Outcome-focused: Performance standards work better than technology mandates because they allow innovation in how goals are achieved.

2. Transparent and Temporary

To minimize distortions and dependencies:

  • Transparency: Full disclosure of costs, benefits, and mechanics facilitates accountability. The Congressional Budget Office's scoring of legislation provides crucial transparency regarding fiscal impacts.

  • Time limits: Clear exit strategies prevent interventions from becoming permanent fixtures. Automatic stabilizers that expand during downturns and contract during expansions calibrate intervention to need.

3. Built-In Accountability

Strong oversight ensures interventions serve the public rather than special interests:

  • Independent evaluation: The U.K.'s Office for Budget Responsibility provides independent analysis of fiscal sustainability.

  • Lobbying reform: Canada's Lobbying Act requires monthly public reporting of all lobbying communications with government officials, reducing behind-closed-doors influence.

Beyond the False Choice

The debate isn't really "government vs. markets"—it's about finding the right relationship between them. The evidence suggests several key insights:

  1. Context matters: Sweden's carbon tax worked brilliantly there but might face different challenges elsewhere due to institutional and cultural differences.

  2. Design determines outcome: How interventions are structured often matters more than whether they exist at all.

  3. Long-term thinking required: Interventions must be evaluated not just on immediate effects but on how they shape incentives over time.

  4. Humility is warranted: Both markets and governments fail. Recognizing the limitations of human knowledge suggests caution in all economic engineering.

The future of capitalism lies not in dogmatic adherence to either free markets or interventionism, but in pragmatic, evidence-based approaches that preserve economic dynamism while addressing genuine market failures.

As Bangladesh's onion crisis showed, even well-intentioned rules can backfire spectacularly. To paraphrase economist Joan Robinson: The only thing worse than being exploited by capitalism might be not being exploited at all—but the worst outcome is poorly designed intervention that delivers neither growth nor equity.

Data-Driven. Unbiased. Timeless.

Coin Juncture cuts through the noise—because understanding the fine print shouldn't require a PhD.

Reply

or to participate.